Saturday, January 21, 2017

Terry Field

Now sojourning in Florida and swimming every day, Englishman Terry Field once again dazzles the mind with a coherent and well-thought out essay on economics - yesterday, today and perhaps tomorrow.  Good reading that challenges the mind.  This is MBA course quality, at least a chapter's worth. - Glenn N. Holliman


A Little History of Economics, and, Unfortunately, Why the Past is the Best Guide to the Future – Terrence Field, Businessman, Economist and Thinker  

Most people who hear the words ‘economy’ or ‘economics’ instinctively recoil, out of an inner alienation, and a distaste at having to apply a fleeting regard something they know matters, but which, at bottom, the simply do not really understand.

Below, Terry explains to Barbara Holliman
that Adam Smith's 'invisible hand' is also 
present in the brewery industry. 2016
For those of us cursed with minds attuned to consider the nature and implications of economics and of capitalism in particular, understanding the past economics of our societies can lead to the understanding of not just the future of economies, but also the social and cultural consequences of how economic life will change.

The early history of the development of economic thinking has taken place in countries where the very nature and condition of economic activity have changed radically in size, geographical reach and complexity over the past two centuries.  Today social, cultural and political influences force economists to reconsider the controllability and stability of economic conditions and structures once taken as self-sustaining.

The Classical Economists

The early view of the ‘classical’ economists such as the famed Scotsman, Adam Smith, reflected the elegant architecture of the period. The late Georgian period produced architecture concerned with symmetry, balance, proportion and the ‘golden ratio’ of classical elegance.  In like manner classical economics looked to an economic engine that tended to natural stability, balance, rational decision making coming from enormous numbers of players who together formed a supra-human ‘hidden hand’.  The ‘hidden hand’ guided the progress of the economy, of human activity, and by implication, the optimization of order, activity, output and human happiness.

Then came the great perturbation of the 1930s. The system failed to do what it was expected to do. As an example, the fall in wages did not produce a rise in the demand for labour, but rather a loss of confidence that accelerated the collapse of demand, output, employment and – to understate it - contentment.

Which leads us to ask, and leave hanging in the air until later in this little note, what, if any ‘purpose’ can be imposed on economic activity. More of that later.

Keynsian State Intervention.                                                                            

As a response to the horror of the Great Depression, a consensus formed that government-led economic activity would be required in the depths of depression in order to ‘stimulate’ the moribund economy into output and employment recovery. This is understood by all to fall under the umbrella of ‘Keynsian’ economics named after Englishman John Maynard Keynes. From this developed the ideas of greater state intervention, the application of politics at the level of the State – socialist intervention. This intervention would not only cause the general economy to recover, but also give government the opportunity to so ‘manage’ the economy in order to protect some social groups against the assumed excess power of other social groups.

In those times, those developed economies who applied these concepts operated in an environment of control of the supply, cost and use of resources, from raw materials right through to final production and consumption. Britain had a comprehensive economic and political empire. The United States was a largely self-contained ‘closed loop’ economy, with equally total control from raw material extraction through to final market supply.

In other words, social, political and economic order coincided geographically. The potential for control seemed total.

IN the context of large-scale, or ‘macro’ economics – western developed economies, where capital, resources, labour, distribution, markets, and social order were all susceptible to governmental influence, and where economic thinking in the great universities focused on how the state could control economic life to the advantage of the   citizenry, all seemed possible.

From the late 1940s through to the collapse of Soviet communism, as ‘macroeconomic’ (large-scale) management of the economy became accepted orthodoxy, the ‘levers of control’ – monetary policy, fiscal policy, together with forms of state-directed activity – were aggressively and confidently applied by chancelleries throughout Europe and Great Britain.

Private activity would be vital, but managed. The future would be predictable.

The difference in how the Soviet Union and most nations in Western Europe applied state control to economic life was really a matter of degree.  In the United States, whilst there was less appetite for far-reaching state intervention in the public mind, yet in reality the role of the state was considerable.

The immense ‘military industrial complex’ was used as an engine of demand management by US governments.

A significant element of the aura that attaches to the Reagan period is the massive increase in military demand from government, the resultant manufacturing activity feeding through to add to the buoyant level of overall demand and of output.

So what happened then?

Busting the controllable ‘end to end’ economy wide open.

Firstly Japan opened its post war economy and a new, vigorous centre of output appeared to challenge the western nations. No longer could western governments operate on a world of end-to-end control. They faced another economy that had its own resource supplies, its own social order, belief systems, attitude to work, skill sets and attributes.

This was the first external attack on the productive capacity and market demand for the goods habitually churned out by the old western economies. To add to the western economic pain, Japanese banks operated differently, in close integrated harmony with their manufacturers, making the competitive threat to the ‘west’ the more potent.

This supply of increasingly superb goods into western markets resulted in the withering of uncompetitive western businesses, increased unemployment, and state support spending, accompanied by reduced tax revenue and increased government borrowing was applied to protect the local victims of superior external competition.

Southeast Asia awakes - Myanmar 2016 

In all this the interesting thing to ponder is the essential untruthfulness of both monetarist and non-monetarist claims that each could be capable of optimizing the performance of the western economies.

Why did the proposition of effective economic control in the west become more and more of a sham? 

The controllable end-to-end western economies were being ripped to pieces.  Where did this collapse of self-contained western control come from? It arose from Deng Xiaoping and the acceptance by China of open economic development, co-ordinated by Chinese Communist Party five-year plans.

The scale of the growth of the Chinese economy now dwarfs that of Japan, with gigantic manufacturing capacity and a cost base that, whilst increasing year by year, still exerts a mortal threat to the manufacturing base of the west - all of the west.

This new world of globalising resource extraction, manufacture and supply now means no national or regional economy can be managed comprehensively at the local level.


 As the old ideas of the rational market, the classical economic model, the Keynsian model, the monetarist model all exhibited a common characteristic.  That is they were unable to allow the provision of effective, universal control and correction to the afflictions suffered across those old economies.  Crises of confidence in the existing social and political structures rose to unprecedented levels.

At the same time, the directed Chinese state appears to offer performance not any longer available to the western states.

This is not entirely unprecedented.
The Soviet leader, Kruschev, suggested that the soviet system would ‘bury’ the west with its superior economic performance. At the time the growth of the soviet economy was robust, whilst that of the west was quite modest.

The centrally directed construction of the ‘skeleton’ of the soviet economy - its basic industry, its transport system, its new cities, its directed education system, and of course its immense military, gave an external observer concern that it may well be the future.

So what happened? The next phase of development to a responsive, sophisticated economic engine required to meet the detailed needs of the variety of the soviet citizenry was entirely beyond the capacity of the soviet state planning system.

To this failure must be added the gigantic misallocation of resources in the process of building soviet cities, industries, agricultural and military; thus the system collapsed into total failure and social trauma, where for a time the lifespan of soviet citizens fell to the mid forties.

So what is different about China?

China is another example of fast structural development, with a remodeling of the economic and physical landscape that is unprecedented in speed. To date, the country has flooded the world with goods, polluted its rivers, poisoned its air, dammed its principal watercourses, added huge city scapes, developed a potent regional military capability, massively increased hydrocarbon usage yet managed to give the impression of un-phased long term control and stable social order.

What it has not done, however, is offer a pluralistic democracy, an open society, clear data and information, nor has it focused on working harmoniously with its near neighbors to establish a co-operative political landscape in south east Asia.

China is a work in progress.

The pressure to employ a gigantic population has caused China to over-extend the period of development of the capital infrastructure of the economy rather than to move to a retail consumer economy at a fast pace.

Right, Terry reads about the economic history of a Pennsylvania river town. 2016

This could be because the social and political structures are not up to the job of facilitating a sophisticated and free private sector economy capable of offering the panoply of goods and services a maturing society of consumers requires. This need for a totally free, sophisticated economy is a primary challenge to the value and usefulness of the centrally directed political structure.

Whilst this may be no rerun of the Soviet Union, it may or may not prove to be a model of economy that matches or exceeds the performance of the western democracies.

The example of the Chinese economy has suggested to many that the state has a valuable role to play as a directing hand – the creator of the structure in which private activity can operate. But we have tried this before, in Europe, in Russia, even in Britain. The result has been a massive waste of resources - the construction of industries in the wrong places, making the wrong goods, consuming vast resources, and polluting the environment and blighting people’s lives.

It is certainly true that the western economies have been guilty of the waste of resources on a massive scale; in telecoms for example, many hundreds of billions of dollars have been spent of cable connections across the world that will never be illuminated with traffic. New industries, new technologies cause people simply to guess about the future, with waste to match the exuberance.

Should we expect that future economic management will take place in a world of uncertainty, disorder and the danger of impoverishing waste?

Of course.

Is unmanageable disorder the certain and unalterable future for economies?

That is the life we must live for a very long time to come, but maybe not for ever, since the development of competing new regions of the globe that causes these immense dislocations will itself stabilise.

The economic blocks will mature.

 Since the present economy of the world is politically and socially fragmented, each component element of this developing global economy cannot be adequately managed by the local political authority - certainly current political offerings   suggesting state actions can control the economy to the extent that it can improve broad swathes of workers lives in any one location is transparently un-provable, and very probably untrue.

Open economies now are subject to ungovernable and often unanticipated external pressures. Politicians are now reacting by ‘hardening’ the external barriers.

In modern open economies global corporations can and do act to remove the power of governments to raise revenue. Those newly developing regions of the world house corporations experiencing very fast growth, which are asset rich, free of debt, with buoyant revenues; the governments of those developing regions have no interest in co-operating with the revenue-starved governments of the ‘old’ western economies. Thus the corporation commands capital, controls its labour costs, pays taxes almost as it wishes, is disconnected from any local authority.

How will the developed economies respond to the new integrating world?

What then can we in the old west expect of our economy? What can we reasonably ask of our political representatives, and what model of capitalism will develop in the near and intermediate future?

That should take us back to the question hanging in the air – can overall social objectives be the driver of economic management. Is this a luxury no longer relevant to modern economies?

Since the classical assumption of the self-correcting structure producing the optimal result is now irrelevant, can the economy be optimized in terms of human happiness, economic security and stability?

In the fragmentation of the global economy, the present answer has to be no.

Certainly there are competing ideas about how the new model of capitalism can be developed to produce a recovery in activity and wealth creation, but nobody is close to being able to suggest a ‘model’ that can reliably produce control and predictability at the level of functional political interest.

If the west does develop a capitalist model that blends a version of state activity that moves towards the Chinese model, because it is the present fashion, and which also maintains the market economy as the vehicle for resource allocation in an attempt to achieve greater predictability, it is clear that such a capitalist model will suffer periodic instability, social dislocation, surprising local successes or the periodic collapse of significant components

Open ended economies, and disrupting technologies lay waste to the old. They build new worlds and now social conditions. No economic model theory or management can neither stop nor adequately manage this.

Does any strategy act to reduce the potential for disruption? Well, there are conditions that lend to greater stability.

Size matters. A very large economy such as the United States commands a reserve currency, and resources that allow for a greater degree of economic control. A very small economy, such as Switzerland, replete with very high educational standards and technical competence, industries with wide competition ‘moats’ and conservative management of currency stability also lend themselves to effective economic management.

Left, Viet Nam open air market of food stuffs in another hybrid system of free enterprise and state control of the economy. 2015

By contrast countries with intermediate scale, poor resources, low productivity, low levels of educational attainment and de-capitalised industries face a formidable task to control events where the world conspires to outcompete them. There, attempts at control via state direction will not protect the population against impoverishment. Such economies will continue to see key sectors destroyed by overwhelming competition from great powers.

Economic management of socially dysfunctional states cannot be successful. Old and irrelevant social models preclude the progress to relevant economic management. For a potent example of this condition, France is instructive. That country wished to challenge the United States by creating a new monetary and political economy in Europe. The directed economy and the political currency (the Euro) has produced major crises and now the exit of the second largest European economy, the UK,  from the political structure.

Old, failed economic ideas die slowly.

The political class tends to tinker with their failings to extend their damaging effects.

At present it seems the old world has no reliable model that ‘works’ to deliver wealth and adequate output. At the same time the Chinese model is half-formed and untested.

Since the economic future is more opaque than at any time in the last two centuries, populist political statements of certainty are plainly unsupportable.

In all this the suggestion that Britain will either do better or worse as a free-floating economic island cannot be supported. Certainly in the near future the economic management of each and every region of the world economy will be more unstable, more volatile, less predictable than in the prior periods of ‘closed-loop’ economies.

That applies with force to the economic management of smaller economic states, whatever the nuanced form of capitalism is applied.

IN addition, it can be asserted with some confidence that, as the period of globalization changes over some decades to a period of mature stable power blocks, with currencies, energy supply, resources, populations, socio-political structures, industrial outputs contained in defined borders, then small states that operate outside such structures will have to have – relatively - better educated workers, better managed economic activity, greater capitalization, be more creative, more productive, more resilient, more market responsive and more sophisticated that those great blocks they compete with in order to survive, let alone thrive.  

Who seriously believes the history of the UK since 1945 makes such a scenario a probable outcome?

The distortion of economics by social preconceptions.

The present economic prejudice required global relocation of activity according to perceptions of what should or should not be done in particular places – thus engineering in Germany, agriculture in France, financial services in the USA and the UK, and high technology, movies and software in the USA.

NO matter that this made little sense in terms of the historical competences of the populations, rather it was a mechanism for financial control via banking houses to direct the activity of the globe, and to vastly enrich themselves in the process.

The result is completely inappropriate and unnecessary wealth accruing to banking ‘taipans’, poverty and misery visited on huge population groups previously profitable employed in gainful activity in the ‘old’ economies, immense concentrations of new wealth founded in the east, huge numbers of Asians newly prosperous, and trillions in surpluses accruing to remote peoples who find themselves sitting on land full of oil and gas.

It would therefore appear highly desirable that a new form of capitalism develops to modify these tendencies, with a larger directing role to be played by the state.



Are new survival strategies now a vital required component part of economic management?

Of even greater significance than developing newly effective general economic tools, however, is the requirement to modify the – until now – market-determined price mechanism to cause hydrocarbon consumption to be radically reduced, and in the process stimulating the direction of significant resources to research and development of new non-carbon energy resources. Without this the future of any economic system is likely to be bleak, as climate change rips through the life of the global populations, resulting in unlivable environments, unviable societies and economic collapse.

The requirement to modify the energy price mechanisms requires long term global co-ordination of the great power blocks. That is, at the best of times, a tall order. Now, with the emergence of the old forces of nationalism, both in Great Britain, Europe and most particularly in the United States, such co-ordinated price management is temporarily – perhaps permanently – off the agenda.
In order to argue for national activity, to include protectionism, aggressive assertions of cultural shibboleths such as military assertiveness, and to support the proposition of hydrocarbon extractions becoming once again a core element of local (US) prosperity, it is a primary requirement to argue that there is no anthropomorphic global warming, climate change and resultant risks.

If that proposition cannot be supported, there can be no rational or safe assertion of the rest of the new nationalism and its beliefs.

To deal with climate change, global governmental intervention to consistently, progressively and universally modify the price and thus usage of hydrocarbon extractions is an unavoidable requirement. This would cause United States hydrocarbon usage to radically reduce, materially offset the growth of such usage in the developing economies of China and India, and propel development of carbon-free energy systems to allow for an energy rich world, with the hydrocarbons left in the ground.

That the Russian state, together with the hydrocarbon producers of the United States wish to defer the reduction in the value of their corporate stock capitalisation and dividend potential is plain.

Russia and the tombs of the Romanovs in St. Petersburg, 2015.  A hybrid economy and government.

The present conversation concerning the possible involvement of Russia in supporting the victory of a man who is on record as denying the truth of AGW is consistent with the seminal crisis of our age – our economy is hydrocarbon, and our demise will come from it if it is not stopped.

And quite soon.

The idea of changing our capitalist model to include the value of ‘externalites’ such as hydrocarbon pollution ( as well as the rest of non-human life could also be so included, but that seems beyond our wit, as well as our moral compass) is radically a new departure for economics.

It suggests that we deliberately develop new energy technology, displacing immense numbers of hydrocarbon workers, ruining the investment value of hydrocarbon corporations, removing significance and potential wealth from Saudi Arabia, and much of the Middle East, whilst cutting the economic legs from the Russian energy industry – not because the present price mechanism requires it, but because our grandchildren will die in a boiling cauldron of misery if we do not.

Do contemporary electoral changes impact the potential for economic and social success?

The election of Mr Trump would- at first glance – suggest that democratic processes, and universal suffrage are an impediment, not an aid, to achieve this change.

Mr Lovelock, the British ‘Gaia’ theorist and scientist – one of the first who identified the climate change danger – has suggested that democratic life may need to be suspended in order to achieve the desired radical re-engineering of the global energy economy.

It is a central problem to imagine how the present global capitalist system, likely now to be even more grotesquely misdirected as a result of monumental greed and ignorance, can be modified to direct the world to a new energy and environmental support future in the context of democratic control.

Until now, even with the immense growth of human economic prosperity the carbon economy has not precluded vast numbers of economic ‘disruptions’, and local inequitable impoverishment.

How the global economy, shifting via modified price mechanisms to a post carbon energy economy will manage its transformation when even larger groups are more severely disrupted, impoverished, removed from comfort, whilst others, through chance, find their lives moving in the opposite direction is not clear.

If Europe, as a regional economy, is threatening to break apart because of the non-acceptance of economic discipline, combined with support payments from the rich (Northsea) states denied to the poorer southern states, what chance to do this more radically and on a global scale, and in the context of the abandonment of an energy supply that we know is abundant, inexpensive, universal and completely integrated to our lives and easy to use – hydrocarbons.

That such as UKIP and ‘The Donald’ have triumphed in a post – crisis downturn gives little confidence that global governance to modify the hydrocarbon price mechanism has even a slight chance of success.

I can only therefore conclude that economics is a busted flush.
It seems economic order can only be achieved when there is easy success to be had.
Now that this pleasant condition is passed into history, it follows that the vital changes to how we consume, live and regard our world will only take place when the event described as their prerequisite for change by David Attenborough takes place.

And the event he identifies is ‘catastrophe’.

Economics will become a conversation not about how to become and remain prosperous, but rather it will become an urgent conversation about how to survive.

Trump and survival. Oxymoron? Possibly.

I am Terence Field and I approve this message.


Comments?

No comments:

Post a Comment